Focus on Saving: Towards consensus
Monday, July 21st 2003, 5:21PM
Summary
- All savings matter: they improve the
financial flexibility that people have. All savings impact on the
financial circumstances of people as they enter retirement. While steps should be taken to
encourage savings in general, particular attention needs to go on the
contribution savings make to the living standards of the retired.
- The recent survey of living standards
of the elderly indicated that in the main, retired people lived with an
acceptable level of comfort. The issue for savings policy is whether
current policy settings and current savings practices are sustaining the
wealth accumulation that will replicate that retirement income pattern for
future generations.
- The indications are that there are
major risks that they will not. Participation in employment based
superannuation schemes has declined dramatically since 1990. Household
debt as a proportion of household income has almost doubled in that time.
Credit card debt is increasing rapidly, and anecdotal evidence is that
people are withdrawing retirement savings to get it under control. A
recent Australian survey indicated that the incidence of inheritances
could be falling for future generations.
- All of these factors suggest that
while there is no need for panic action, savings policy needs to be
designed around the mitigation and management of the risk that retirement
income in the future will fall short of what is regarded as acceptable. If
that happens, extra costs will be imposed on individuals and on the
government. Both should therefore make a contribution towards enhancing
private savings.
- Just how strong that contribution
ought to be depends on an assessment of how serious the deterioration in
savings is. That assessment will change over time, and any savings policy
needs to be flexible enough to intensify or ease the measures being taken
to encourage savings.
- The workplace is an efficient vehicle
to use for mobilising individual savings. The difficulty is that the
motivations on employers or unions to pursue an active agenda to promote
retirement saving as a component of the remuneration package are weak.
- In these circumstances, there are two
broad mechanisms that can be deployed to boost savings: incentives and
compulsion. Further, it is possible to envisage escalating levels of
intervention associated with either incentives or compulsion, and
combinations of the two. Both tend to be costly and they intrude on
individual choice. The consequence is that the blend and degree of
incentive and compulsion that are used should be no more than is needed to
respond to the level of risk that is assessed to exist.
- A process for agreeing on the
intensity of intervention that is needed, and on the most effective and
efficient blend of incentive and compulsion used to deliver it is the
first step needed for firming up a savings policy, and for tracking and
adjusting it in the future.
Background.
In early June,
the ISI circulated an issues paper on savings policy to a number of interested
organisations and individuals.
In order to
progress the debate, this paper consolidates the issues around a number of
themes that allow a comprehensive savings policy framework to be
developed. It does not start with a
blank sheet of paper: instead it works off a proposition that there is a need
to lift national savings, and within that to raise personal savings levels and
personal wealth.
Starting assumptions on the need to save.
Discussions on
the issues paper established that there is a body of opinion that does not
accept that the need to increase savings has been well established. At the very
least the concern is that “the problem” is poorly or loosely defined, with the
result that it is hard to discuss “solutions”.
This paper starts
from an acceptance that there are macroeconomic and personal advantages to be
had from an increase in the savings rate. These are not always the same thing.
It is possible to increase national savings by reducing the ability of
individuals to save (for example by a government raising taxes to improve
government, and hence national, savings levels).
In general,
though, the aim should be to increase both, and both should be seen as a
constraint on each other (government savings should not be achieved by crowding
out the capacity of individuals to save and individual saving should not be
boosted by an even larger decrease in government saving).
The survey of the
living standards of the elderly concluded that in the main, retirement income
was sufficient to permit acceptable levels of comfort, except where the
individual had experienced one or more “life shocks” (poor health,
unemployment, matrimonial property settlement etc) in the immediate
pre-retirement period.
The model on
which this adequacy was built was a “package” of somewhere between sixty and
seventy percent of income coming from New Zealand Superannuation, past savings
and/or superannuation scheme supplementing that, and the retiree occupying an
owned home. (There was, though, considerable variation in other income, with a
substantial proportion of the retired principally dependent on NZS. Despite
that, private income (or running down savings) is part and parcel of
comfortable retirement. The Household
Savings Survey identified inheritance as a strong contributor to differences in
wealth between households.
The question is
whether this “model” is holding up as the generations move through. There is
clear evidence of a substantial reduction of participation in work-based
superannuation schemes, and household debt has soared. The typical work cycle
now involves people starting work later in life (after more extended education
and training), with a student debt, and with the likelihood that they will have
interrupted work spans. These conditions could well reduce the prospects of
saving during working life. A recent Australian survey concluded that
inheritances may be playing a decreasing role in the wealth accumulation
process.
The risk is that
more and more people enter retirement in a similar financial condition to those
among the current retired who have had a “life shock” (few assets, possibly
debts, very little investment income). In future, will the condition that now
emerges after a “life shock” be more common and in fact be a result of “life style”?
The counter
argument is to say that we do not know what is happening with new or
alternative forms of savings behaviour.
People have more debt, but they may have more assets as well. They are
not in superannuation schemes but they may have personal financial portfolios.
There are firm
statistical indicators of change and
the documented change reveals deterioration.
If there has been a compensating
change “off camera”, (people accumulating assets in new and different forms)
then there is no problem. If savings are increased from a currently “adequate”
base, in twenty or forty year’s time retirees will be more than comfortable. If
there has not been a compensating
change, then in twenty or forty year’s time there is a problem and it is too
late to do anything about it.
The only options
will be to tolerate poverty in retirement or increase the universal pension to
take up the slack. But this will be
at a time when the demographic structure makes any widespread increase in
public supports to retirement income extremely expensive, and when there are
risks that the demographic structure will be generating fiscal pressures around
financing health care.
Sensible risk management
suggests that it is time to move on with a pro-savings agenda.
It is important to stress
that this paper does not focus on a target level of savings, or prefer a
particular form of savings. It works from an assumption that there are risks
that the somewhat comforting profile revealed by the living standards survey
will not last. A response therefore involves risk mitigation. It has to be
sufficiently flexible to adapt, over time, as perceptions about the risks of
generating comfortable living standards in retirement change.
The fact that
there is still some concern around whether a problem exists, and whether it has
been sufficiently defined may, however, rule out more intrusive interventions
(like particular forms of compulsion), at least in the immediate future.
The challenge is
to design a process that is purposeful enough to get around the “paralysis of
analysis”, but flexible enough to respond to more clarity emerging on problem
definition.
The core dilemma: grow or save?
There is a body of
opinion that sees “saving” as (largely) irrelevant. In this school of thought,
the issue is not what people save, but the size of the economy in the future
(and the size of the economically active population). If there is more to go
around, it is easier to tax and redistribute it. If we have a small economy,
claims to a share of a shrinking cake are not worth much.
Growth (and/or
immigration) are seen as the answers. Growth is important, and a higher level
of national savings would capture a larger share of the future output for New
Zealanders (compared with more reliance on the savings of foreigners to finance
investment). However, growth is not the answer.
This is because wellbeing in retirement is only partly an absolute:
adequacy is also relative to the
living standards of the rest of society.
By way of
example, New Zealand Superannuation is linked to the average wage. A growing
economy would normally generate higher wages, and raise the absolute value of NZS without changing
its relative value. It is the
relative value that is usually the policy target. A growing economy makes for
richer people, not fewer people, and it is the numbers in retirement that
generate the claims on future production.
Immigration is
also not a viable route to sustaining higher levels of income transfers out of
current production. Even a strong level of net inward migration (say 20,000 a
year) increases the population by only half a percent a year. The relevant
aspect, though, is not the change in the size of the population but the proportion of the population that is
economically active that determines the capacity of the government to base
income adequacy on transfers. That half a percent increase in the population
has to be of sufficiently different composition from the current population to
change participation rates in a material way. The arithmetic is against it.
It is not a case
of save or grow: it is a case of save and grow. Both matter.
The changing focus: saving, retirement savings,
retirement income or retirement income policy?
The debate on
savings policy tends to migrate between discussing saving, retirement savings and retirement income. This is not entirely surprising: they are linked.
Saving, for
whatever reason and over whatever time period, will impact on the net asset
position of individuals at the point of retirement. Retirement savings are different in two important respects:
generally they must be a larger quantum and be locked in for longer periods
than other forms of saving. Despite that, the distinction is not as clear cut
as that: all savings impact on the financial assets of the retiree.
There is also
some evidence that savings are influenced by habit: the earlier individuals
start to save, the more they are likely to save and hence “saving” in a more
general sense is likely to be strongly associated with retirement saving.
At the other end
of the spectrum, retirement savings will generate some income in retirement,
and consumption in retirement can involve drawing on saving. Hence there is no
clear cut distinction between retirement savings and retirement income.
However, indications are that while there is a large variation between
individuals (the distribution of wealth is twice as unequal as the distribution
of income), in general something like two-thirds of retirement income does not come from retirement savings: it comes from direct income
transfers via New Zealand Superannuation.
It is true that
savings increase personal financial flexibility. It is also likely that a
higher savings rate will finance a higher level of investment or at least
enable New Zealand nationals to capture more of the income that flows from that
investment. This is not to say, though, that there is much that a savings policy can or ought to do to boost
savings generally. The key thing for policy is to focus on social and economic
end results that are adverse and avoidable, and difficult or costly to correct
if remedial action is not taken in a timely manner.
As mentioned
earlier, a “snapshot” taken around the turn of the century produced a picture
of the retired as having generally adequate living standards. The real question
is if nothing is done and another snapshot is take in twenty years time, what
will that picture look like? People will cope. Societies adapt and muddle
through all sorts of circumstances. Coping may, though, involve imposing
avoidable hardship on a bigger section of the retired, or squeeze government
spending in other areas of public benefit.
In retirement,
options have closed, and time to rebuild has elapsed. It is because of this
that the focus of policy is on
retirement income. Savings, in this context, is a factor that contributes to
the adequacy of retirement income.
“Policy” is,
though, not only what governments do. It can also require changes in the way
that employers, unions and the providers of savings products go about their
business.
In this paper,
the emphasis is on policies needed
to change savings patterns so that retirement savings make a contribution
to the adequacy of retirement incomes.
Savings and income.
“Income” is in
many ways a transitional concept: in itself it doesn’t contribute anything to
personal or national wellbeing. It is purely a means to an end, a bit like
money. Money doesn’t make people any
better off: they can’t eat it or wear it or shelter under it. “Income” and “money” are simply means to an
end: they are a medium.
Income is not
even the medium through which people claim rights to use resources. Income
doesn’t guarantee anything. An extreme episode in history reminds us of this.
During the hyper-inflation in Germany in the 1920s, income was losing its
capacity to command resources so rapidly that workers were demanding pay each
lunchtime, so they could throw the pay over the factory fence to waiting spouses
who would run to the shops before the value of the income eroded further.
Income is the
medium through which individuals, groups or nations obtain a capacity to
negotiate for the rights to acquire resources (“goods and services”). Those
resources can be used (consumed) or stored for later use (saved). Typically,
the capacity to claim is itself stored (a financial asset).
This concept
helps to focus thinking about “saving”.
The traditional
approach is to think of saving in three “tiers” or “pillars”:
·
The state
provided universal pension or state mandated universal savings obligation.
·
Employment
based (usually retirement aligned) saving.
·
Individual,
voluntary saving.
Thinking about
income as merely a means to the end of current or postponed consumption recasts
the “three pillars”. The first tier or pillar need not be saving at all. It can
merely be the redistribution of the capacity to negotiate for the use of
resources. The government taxes the “medium” of some and transfers it to others
(the retired, or people over a certain age if it is an age benefit).
It is only that
portion of the “first tier” that is met out of government saving, or that is
compulsorily saved by the individual, that is a store of the capacity to bid
for resources. In New Zealand, first tier “saving” for retirement income is 1.6
percent of GDP (when the phase-in of the NZS Fund is complete) plus earnings
reinvested.
This does not
mean that NZS is not an essential component of the retirement income package. It clearly is. The state
is providing bargaining power equal to (say), two-thirds of the comfortable
consumption needs of the retired through a regular, and predictable, and
(hopefully!) reliable flow of money.
This takes
pressure off the need to save the rest of
the package that will source consumption in retirement. It also does more than that. If it is there
as the backstop, there is less concern that when it comes to retirement, the
savings will not be convertible into goods: negative returns on investment,
inflation eroding the value of financial assets. A basic, guaranteed state
pension can improve the quality of the vehicles in which the stored value is
held.
Thinking about
income and savings in this way also has implications for the design of second
and third tier savings products. It may be that the preference of New
Zealanders for holding wealth in the form of housing is not just tax driven: a
house can be used for shelter, and in the future the owner can access “income”
to use in bidding for goods by renting it out. There is much less predictable
utility in financial assets!
Assessing and responding to future risks.
NZ Superannuation
is a core element of the current retirement living setup. It is not sensible to
work off a “dire” scenario under which NZS is not available or is heavily pared
back. Demographic change will increase the fiscal pressures that NZS generates.
In one sense, though, a “mature” NZS will not cost a lot more than some
European country first tier schemes already cost. While there may be financial
pressures to pare back NZS, political arithmetic suggests that there will be a
countervailing democratic force.
In the short
term, the demographic structure is such that the relative costs of NZS will
fall. In the longer term, the NZ Superannuation Fund will contribute something
like 25 percent to the total cost. The question is what level of risk surrounds
the remaining 75 percent of NZS that is pay-as-you-go, and that contributes
about two-thirds of the package that secures the “smiling faces” in the snapshot
of the currently retired?
There can be no
absolute certainty about the sustainability of NZS. It is possible that while
NZS can be sustained, the needs of the retired may increase. An example would
be if increasing health care costs either increased pressure to adjust
eligibility for, or levels of NZS, or increased the proportion of health costs
that the individual had to cover. In this case, more income is needed to keep
the faces smiling.
Individuals will assess the risks that they face from long-run
threats to NZS. It is likely, given the demographics, that they will increase
for the younger age cohorts. At this stage, though, there is no firm basis on
which to map out a collective replacement
regime. What can be said with some confidence is that there is very little
chance that improving NZS will reduce
the need for additional forms of savings to sustain comfortable
retirement.
If the second and
third tier arrangements are regarded as central to the adequacy of the
retirement income package, then it is much more likely that the risks of
maintaining a happy retirement snapshot going forward arise out the apparent
deterioration in private provision at these second and third tiers.
There is always
the possibility that at a later date the collective assessment of the
sustainability of NZS would dictate that the second and third tiers need to be
even further strengthened. A savings policy needs to be flexible enough to
accommodate that prospect.
For now, it is
sufficient to work off the observations that:
·
At the
personal level, household debt has soared from around 58 percent of household
income in 1991, to over 113 percent by 2002.
·
Outstanding
balances on credit cards have increased by over 50 percent in the last three
years.
·
In 1991,
22.6 percent of the employed workforce was members of employment based
superannuation schemes. By 2001 that had slumped to 14.6 percent.
At the very
least, a savings policy needs to lay out options for responding to those
features. How hard the response has to be, and where the emphasis goes, are
matters that ought to be addressed through a focussed process.
In the first
instance, attention can be given to employment based superannuation.
Work-based savings plans.
The issues paper
identified work-based savings schemes as efficient and effective in boosting
savings levels and in increasing their duration (i.e. in promoting retirement savings). They are also in
decline!
Work-based
schemes have to overcome two hurdles: the employer has to have one on offer,
and the worker has to take up the offer. Either or both parties can be left to
their own devices, or policy can offer incentives to change practice, or compel
the parties to change practice.
The issues paper
noted that while there are some advantages to the key labour market
institutions to encourage superannuation, the motivations are weak and the
costs are potentially quite high.
Policies to
promote access and take-up can be viewed around escalating levels of incentive and compulsion: on both parties.
The challenge is
to decide:
·
where the
balance of incentive and compulsion ought to lie as between the employer and
the worker,
·
what the
balance between incentive and compulsion ought to be, and
·
what level
of either incentive or compulsion is appropriate.
It is possible to
represent the choices as moving ever more aggressively away from the status
quo. Currently, the savings regime is
essentially voluntary, and the intention anyway is that there is tax
neutrality. The tax regime is not supposed to encourage or discourage saving,
or to favour one form of saving vehicle over others.
In practice, for
employment based schemes there are some compliance costs (associated with
prospectus requirements and the like) that may be seen to be a negative form of
compulsion (“repulsion”?). The tax treatment can be tax neutral or overtax the
worker, so on balance there are small tax disincentives.
The future
involves moving up the scale of either or both of the compulsion or incentive
routes. The desirable end point is not clearly fixed, and fixing it requires an
element of judgement informed by discussion, analysis and compromise. The end
point can shift through time as the effectiveness of any new
compulsion/incentive mix becomes apparent, and as the collective assessment of
the need to boost employment based savings alters.
Private voluntary saving.
There are a
number of anomalies in the tax treatment of savings in general, but these are
more acute when it comes to private savings. The anomalies arise out the
taxation of capital gains and the tax treatment of international investment.
When looking at
savings policy, “compulsion” tends to be irrelevant for this tier. (Compulsory
private saving in effect shifts this form of saving into “first tier” provision
of retirement income). It tends to be very difficult to design cost effective
tax incentives for this sort of saving (see below). The main reason is that
savings shift more easily into tax advantaged vehicles so there is little
confidence that incentives generate new and additional saving.
Under these
conditions, the focus of policy shifts to tax disincentives and the quality,
cost and range of products that the industry offers. “Policy” has a strong
non-governmental dimension to it as well.
Tax distortions
are difficult to remove from the private savings environment. Much of the
distortion comes from the treatment of capital gains, and all past attempts to
grapple with this issue have foundered on the traditional rocks (allowing
offsets for capital losses, taxing unrealised gains, taxing when there is no
accompanying cash flow to pay the taxes, taxing nominal rather than real gains,
making allowances for extra risk associated with any gain, and so on).
There is also a
strong political aversion to capital gains tax, and it is hard to see this as a
focus of savings policy in the near future. Instead, it is best to continue to
police the capital/ revenue boundary and concentrate savings policy on some of
the more direct issues associated with tax disincentives, the regulatory
environment, and the adequacy of the product mix.
This leads back
to the issues of incentives and compulsion and the forms they may take.
Tax and savings
Tax can impact on
saving in three ways:
·
It can
reward saving (“Incentives”)
·
It can
discourage saving (“Disincentives”)
·
It can
follow saving through time (“Deferral”)
Regardless of
whether the consideration is around offering incentives, removing disincentives
or aligning the tax with when income is consumed, two principles should guide
the design of policy.
(i)
Equity.
Horizontal equity requires that the tax treatment is
the same regardless of the form in
which people choose to store their claims to resources.
Vertical equity is more subjective. It requires that
tax treatments do not favour those who have more income than others. (It can
also imply progressivity: that those on lower incomes have a proportionately
greater benefit from the tax treatment than those who have more).
(ii)
Cost effectiveness.
In some writing this is split into three components:
costs to the government; efficiency in terms of leveraging actual increases in
savings; and impacts on aggregate saving, but in fact they are all aspects of
cost effectiveness.
Tax incentives.
Tax incentives
tend to be inequitable. Unless they are available on an extraordinarily wide
basis, they favour some forms of savings vehicle over others (there is no
horizontal equity). Those with higher incomes tend to able to save more, and
can access the full extent of the available incentive. Incentives that involve
exemptions tend to load the reward onto the marginal tax rate, again giving
most advantage to the better off. Rebates can introduce progressivity, but only
to the extent that the low paid can save enough to access them, and they then
lose their strength as an incentive for the higher paid!
They are also
dubious from a cost effectiveness point of view. In order to be sufficiently
attractive they must be quite large, and therefore expensive. There is a high
risk that they will increase national savings only slowly (the loss of revenue
to the government reduces the savings impact of the new private savings that
they stimulate). If the design of the incentive allows existing saving to
migrate to the tax advantaged vehicle, national savings might actually fall.
Removing disincentives.
The taxation of
savings tends to overtax certain vehicles and under-tax others, and is riddled
with anomalies and complications.
This would seem
to be a high priority area for policy development. It can be expensive: the
over-taxation of some earnings is nevertheless generating revenue! It is also
an incredibly complex area for tax structure design.
However, removing
disincentives has the capacity to improve horizontal equity and some forms of
change can improve vertical equity (by aligning the tax on earnings with the
marginal tax rates applying inside a progressive tax scale).
Deferral
Aligning the
taxation of money flows with when they are held in a form that allows them to
be consumed has a certain logic to it. In the extreme case this would involve a
much heavier reliance on consumption taxes in the tax mix (to reduce the
problems associated with “tracking” when people use their savings, or borrow
against them to bring forward consumption). The problem with that is that
taxing at the point of consumption clashes with the vertical equity principle
of good tax policy. There is therefore a need for compromise.
In its most
simple form, deferral switches the last “T” and “E” of the TTE structure and
corrects for the double taxation of the first “T” (i.e. it is a TEt regime). {A
pure form of deferral would go as far as switching to an EET regime}. The
question is really whether this is cost effective. The issue is whether it is
the return or the tax on the return that is crucial in changing saving
behaviour. “E” will only
(temporarily!!) alter the return by up to one-third (5 percent not 7). The
prospect of much bigger pre tax returns or aversion to losses may well be much
more powerful drivers of savings practice.
Apart from the
impact of deferral on behaviour, it can also be justified on the grounds of
improving inter-temporal equity.
Deferral should
perhaps best be seen as the area in need of attention after removal of
disincentives and before the introduction of incentives.
Non-tax incentives and disincentives.
There is a range
of incentives that can be provided directly. In general, they limit the risks
of savings “migrating”, they can be much more tightly targeted at a particular
barrier to savings, they can be structured to encourage or reward particular
types of savings, their costs tend to be more predictable and contained and
they are more transparent. On the other hand, structuring incentives around
types of savings can be distorting, and if they encourage and reward inefficient savings vehicles they can be
inequitable and ineffective.
Direct incentives
can reward either employer or worker, but as a general rule they tend to reward
the employer (financial incentives to workers are usually just another form of
tax incentive)
Incentives to
employers would range across, but not be limited to:
·
Grants to
cover administrative costs such as scheme design, joining fees and
administration fees, and payroll costs.
·
Provision of
bureau services to take over these administrative functions.
·
Establishment
of umbrella schemes that employers can enlist with.
·
Provision of
advisory services on scheme design and administration.
·
“Matching”
employer contributions (which for cost and equity reasons would have to be
limited either in dollar amount, and/or for employees earning below particular
wage levels).
Incentives to
employees can either be “front end”, or based on some type of reward system (a
bit like consumer loyalty programmes, which “turbo-charge” savings at key
milestones. Cost and equity considerations would also tend to limit access to
the incentives to fixed dollar amount or to some definition of low pay.
Removing non-tax
disincentives focuses on cumbersome or costly aspects of the regulatory
environment. It is important to avoid removing necessary regulatory protections
in the drive to lower compliance barriers.
Compulsion.
Compulsion is a
relatively intrusive form of public policy because it interferes either with
how a worker spends a pay packet or how an employer structures an operation.
Interference is not particularly unusual: workers have to pay ACC levies to
insure themselves against non-work accidents and employers have to comply with
the occupational health and safety legislation. Both are examples of a central
authority telling workers how to spend their money or telling employers how to
structure parts of their operations.
The test is “good
cause”.
Compulsion on employees.
Escalating levels
of compulsion would be:
·
An
obligation to formally withdraw from a superannuation scheme, if membership is
not wanted, so that the default option in taking on a job is to be a member of
a scheme.
·
A
requirement to be a member of a scheme if employed beyond a certain age (say 40
when the expectation is that more urgent demands on limited income have eased).
·
An
obligation to contribute if earning above a certain level of income (this
allows the government to supplement contributions of workers with less than the
threshold income, and can be an equitable and cost effective way of spreading
participation in schemes).
·
Compulsory
contributions of at least a set dollar amount or a percent of salary.
·
Lock-in
provisions on any amounts contributed.
Compulsion on employers.