tmmonline.nz  |   landlords.co.nz        About Good Returns  |  Advertise  |  Contact Us  |  Terms & Conditions  |  RSS Feeds

NZ's Financial Adviser News Centre

GR Logo
Last Article Uploaded: Saturday, December 21st, 2:19PM

Investments

rss
Latest Headlines

Roundtable says pension should be a benefit

Business roundtable executive Roger Kerr says universality is essentially another of New Zealand's unfortunate Muldoonist legacies – another think big scheme.

Friday, November 5th 1999, 12:00AM

by Philip Macalister

Business Roundtable executive dirctor Roger Kerr says the state pension has historically been a "general safety net", and it should be returned to that basis.

He says the debate on superannuation over the past few years has clarified many issues. For instance the referendum clearly showed New Zealanders did not support a compulsory system, work by bodies such as the Investment Savings and Insurance Association illustrated economic growth was a key factor in determining the level of superannuation, and various reports by organisations such as the Periodic Review Group, the Todd Taskforce and the Accord showed that tax concessions for savings were undesirable.

The key outstanding issue to be resolved is the design of the safety net.

The following is an extract from a speech by Roger Kerr titled: "On from Entitlements to Needs: Abandoning New Zealand's Last Think Big Scheme".

With the primacy of economic growth established and compulsion and tax concessions sidelined, the way has been cleared to 'make super simple'. The key outstanding issue to be resolved is the design of the safety net.

This issue is usually discussed in terms of the level and qualifying age for NZS and whether it should be provided on a universal or targeted basis. But behind that choice is a deeper argument: whether superannuation is a matter of entitlement or needs. Grey Power views superannuation is an entitlement and, as such, it argues that it should be universal. All recent reviews – the 1988 Royal Commission on Social Policy, the Todd Task Force, the PRG and the ISI's report – view superannuation as needs-related and part of the general welfare system.

Several arguments have been advanced for an entitlement approach to superannuation and benefits. One is that welfare should be provided on a universal basis as a badge or right of citizenship. Another is that a universal entitlement should be given to citizens to avoid stigma, to compensate victims of misfortune and to enable people to achieve the level of consumption required to participate in society. Means testing is not always rejected by those who endorse citizenship theory. The 1972 McCarthy Royal Commission on Social Security, for instance, adopted a citizenship perspective in discussing benefit levels but endorsed the continuation of income tests.

In his book From Welfare State to Civil Society, David Green argues that universalism intensifies the corruption of vote-buying and middle class subsidies. "Where," he asks, "is the concern for social solidarity in telling people that they can enjoy many benefits at the general expense?" According to Green, a notion of universal entitlements "breeds division and antagonism" rather than social cohesion. Moreover, an appeal to citizenship and the assertion of rights to welfare do not take us far in establishing sound policies. They are of little help, for instance, in deciding in what circumstances people should be supported by taxpayers, who should be supported, to what level and on what basis.

A large proportion of the tax revenue that is raised to finance universal entitlements is returned to the same taxpayers in the current period or at a later time. This income 'churning' results in high levels of tax with associated deadweight costs that reduce economic growth. For this reason, needs-based support is usually preferred on the grounds that it is least harmful to the economy. Moreover, the transfer of income from people on low and moderate incomes to those who are well off is inequitable.

A needs-based approach to superannuation is the historical norm in New Zealand. The legislation that introduced the old age pension almost exactly 100 years ago was tightly drawn and few received assistance. Applicants for a pension had to satisfy numerous requirements. They had to be at least 65 years of age – a high qualifying age relative to life expectancy at that time – and to possess little or no property or other income. By 1940 only half of all people who satisfied the age criterion qualified for a pension.

The age of eligibility for the age benefit, which replaced the old age pension, was set at 60 for men and women on the introduction of the social security system in the late 1930s. The level of the benefit was increased but it remained modest. In 1945, for instance, the weekly age benefit was equivalent to a day and a half of a labourer's pay and was broadly equal to the family benefit paid to a mother of three children. The means test was retained. It included an asset test which was not abolished until 1960.

Only three-quarters of all elderly people qualified for a state pension of any sort in 1950. A modest universal superannuation scheme had been introduced in 1940. It was intended over many years to replace the age benefit with a non-means tested and taxable payment for residents over 65 years of age. In the meantime universal superannuation was to run alongside the age benefit. The age benefit, in effect, was to become universal at age 65. However, it was not until 1960 that the rate of universal superannuation reached that of the age benefit. Even then, the age benefit was tax free whereas universal superannuation was taxable. With a highly progressive tax structure and a top income tax rate of 60 percent, taxable universal superannuation was in some ways like a targeted supplement to the age benefit.

After the short-lived funded scheme introduced by the third Labour government, the character of New Zealand's safety net was dramatically changed for the worse by the introduction of National Superannuation in 1977. National Superannuation was an unfunded, non-contributory, universal scheme payable at age 60. It was set at a much higher level than the former age benefit. The generosity of the scheme and an increase in the proportion of superannuitants in the population eventually led to the introduction of the surcharge and to other measures to contain its cost.

This quick historical tour indicates that the long-run tradition in New Zealand has been to view income security in retirement as part of the general safety net. Unlike the approach of many other countries, benefits have always been flat-rate rather than income-related and with the brief 1970s exception, schemes have been non-contributory. Moreover, for most of this century means testing has been an integral part of New Zealand's support for the elderly and other welfare arrangements.

It is often asserted that the retired have paid for NZS through their past taxes. Grey Power, for instance, recently argued that "New Zealand's senior citizens have paid their dues" and that "3.7 billion dollars was ripped away from retired New Zealanders during the life of the surcharge." These claims are utter nonsense and their barefaced repetition should be condemned by politicians.

The truth is that successive governments have funded publicly provided superannuation out of current tax revenue, including the short-lived social security charge and tax. They have been pay-as-you-go schemes. An investment fund to finance future public pensions has never been established.

As far back as the 1967 Ross Committee and the 1972 McCarthy Royal Commission, official inquiries were pointing out that annual social security contributions were falling well short of the level needed to fund current pensions and other social security benefits, and they were subsequently scrapped. The McCarthy Commission, for example, stated that:

… although a special Social Security Fund was established to receive the 5 percent (later 7.5 percent) contribution (or social security tax), this fund was never actuarially funded according to private insurance principles and was never sufficient to meet the total cost of the scheme. It was thus not a true insurance scheme. The basic principle was that people should contribute according to their means and receive benefits according to their needs and not in relation to the amount of their contribution.

There is nothing wrong with funding a safety net out of current tax revenues, but the idea that NZS is something different – more like an entitlement – is an illusion.

In his book Selfish Generations, David Thomson of Massey University has examined whether the welfare benefits that the present generation of retirees will receive over their lives will be matched by the taxes that they pay. The former are broadly defined to include social security cash allowances, education, housing, health and other government services. While such calculations raise difficult conceptual and measurement issues, I am not aware of any major challenge to Professor Thomson's general findings. These are that the older generations in New Zealand systematically benefited at the expense of those that came later. He finds, for instance, that the average ratio of lifetime welfare benefits to taxes for a person born in 1930 will be almost 1.8 to 1.

By contrast with an entitlement approach, a needs-based approach to a safety net emphasises individual responsibility. The role of the government is to help people who cannot help themselves and who cannot be supported in other ways. A needs-based approach is generally more equitable and efficient than an entitlement approach because people on low to modest incomes are not taxed to increase the incomes of retired millionaires. In the case of the next group, the broad category of middle-income earners, a non-targeted benefit results in the government taxing one group of people only to return the money to people in a similar category, with all the compliance, administration and deadweight costs associated with such 'churning'. A strong argument can be made that it is only the category of low income earners or those without resources who should be the object of public policy, on either efficiency or equity grounds, through targeted assistance.

Viewed in safety net terms, it is hard to see how the government's welfare responsibility for people in old age differs from its role in respect of those facing other lifetime contingencies, namely to protect people from hardship. Families are normally expected to be responsible for providing for their own incomes, and the role of the government is limited to providing an adequate income to those without other means in the event of sickness, invalidity or unemployment.

The basic dilemma in designing a safety net is easily stated. Besides its other limitations, a universal scheme is very costly, it imposes a high tax burden and is a drag on growth. Its perceived advantage from a savings perspective is that it avoids the problem of a high effective marginal tax rate on retirees' other income that can arise with targeting – the so-called 'savings disincentive'. This effect, however, is likely to be outweighed by the higher tax rates and greater disincentive to savings associated with an expensive universal scheme which apply to the whole population of taxpayers. Conversely, a targeted scheme imposes a lesser fiscal burden and is less harmful to economic growth. The best way of avoiding excessive marginal tax rates with a targeted scheme is to get overall tax requirements down, to set the benefit at an appropriate level, and to begin phasing it out at a realistic threshold.

The PRG headed in the direction of a needs-based approach. In its interim report, which is to be read alongside its final report, the PRG stated that it supported targeting and regretted the "impending abolition of the surcharge." In its final report it suggested five options which essentially boil down to three: a universal benefit, a part-universal/part-targeted benefit, and a targeted (income- and asset-tested) benefit. There are no sound efficiency or equity grounds for a universal benefit, and the fiscal costs and deadweight losses associated with such a scheme are large. Given that conclusion, it follows that part-universal and part-targeted options make no sense either.

With proper political leadership, I believe there is a good prospect of achieving a public consensus around the idea of a needs-based safety net just as there is solid public support for a state role of last resort in other welfare settings. There are sound equity arguments for such a role. Most people are happy to help people who need help, but are not keen on seeing their taxes going to those who do not. Equity and efficiency arguments for other approaches, such as those involving universal payments, are weak and stand little chance of being politically sustainable over the long run. There may be a case for limiting the impact of targeting on those in or near retirement, but new cohorts of retirees should be given a clear signal about the basis on which they should make their retirement plans.

4 Conclusion

The resolution of the choice between an entitlement- and a needs-based approach to the design of a safety net is the main outstanding issue in retirement income policy. The ISI is pointing in a needs direction – it has said that the issue will be part of the next stage of its work. Universality is essentially another of New Zealand's unfortunate Muldoonist legacies – another think big scheme. Like the others, it should be abandoned; its new lease of life this year will hopefully be brief.

The surcharge was not the best way of re-establishing a needs-based approach. The Labour government adopted the surcharge as a roundabout way of avoiding breaking the letter of its election promises. National also broke an election promise on the issue. The political costs that have been paid for not confronting the issue up-front have been heavy. It is time we had the maturity to approach targeting directly. A sound safety net should be designed having regard to factors such as the qualifying age, the levels of NZS, income abatement rates and asset tests. Australia has achieved a political consensus on an income- and asset-tested safety net and there is no reason why New Zealand could not do likewise. Doing the necessary analytical work and promoting such a consensus should be a priority for the ISI, ASFONZ and other interested parties.

.

Do you agree with Roger Kerr? To have your say on the subject visit the Discussion Forum.

« Political parties asked if they could work together on superAMP & Good Returns launch superannuation website »

Special Offers

Commenting is closed

 

print

Printable version  

print

Email to a friend
News Bites
Latest Comments
  • The good guys get told off
    “I can't quite reconcile the rationale, or lack thereof, with the comments so far. Pathfinder were found to have made misleading...”
    2 days ago by John Milner
  • The good guys get told off
    “As a follow on to this conversation: I'm assuming that the Regulator will be consistent by 'naming and shaming' the other...”
    2 days ago by Pragmatic
  • The good guys get told off
    “FMA does not understand the consequences of these type of actions A number of Insurance Companies were taken to court and...”
    2 days ago by LNF
  • The good guys get told off
    “Superlife was censored for using unregistered salespeople however what is not commonly known was that the FMA were aware...”
    2 days ago by Patrickdiack
  • The good guys get told off
    “FMA executive director, Response and Enforcement, Louise Unger said:... Unger was appointed to that role in April of this...”
    3 days ago by Aggressively_passive
Subscribe Now

News and information about KiwiSaver

Previous News
Most Commented On
Mortgage Rates Table

Full Rates Table | Compare Rates

Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
AIA - Back My Build 4.94 - - -
AIA - Go Home Loans 7.49 5.79 5.49 5.59
ANZ 7.39 6.39 6.19 6.19
ANZ Blueprint to Build 7.39 - - -
ANZ Good Energy - - - 1.00
ANZ Special - 5.79 5.59 5.59
ASB Bank 7.39 5.79 5.49 5.59
ASB Better Homes Top Up - - - 1.00
Avanti Finance 7.90 - - -
Basecorp Finance 8.35 - - -
BNZ - Classic - 5.99 5.69 5.69
Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
BNZ - Mortgage One 7.54 - - -
BNZ - Rapid Repay 7.54 - - -
BNZ - Std 7.44 5.79 5.59 5.69
BNZ - TotalMoney 7.54 - - -
CFML 321 Loans ▼5.80 - - -
CFML Home Loans ▼6.25 - - -
CFML Prime Loans ▼7.85 - - -
CFML Standard Loans ▼8.80 - - -
China Construction Bank - 7.09 6.75 6.49
China Construction Bank Special - - - -
Co-operative Bank - First Home Special - 5.69 - -
Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
Co-operative Bank - Owner Occ 6.95 5.79 5.59 5.69
Co-operative Bank - Standard 6.95 6.29 6.09 6.19
Credit Union Auckland 7.70 - - -
First Credit Union Special - 5.99 5.89 -
First Credit Union Standard 7.69 6.69 6.39 -
Heartland Bank - Online 6.99 5.49 5.39 5.45
Heartland Bank - Reverse Mortgage - - - -
Heretaunga Building Society ▼8.15 ▼6.50 ▼6.30 -
ICBC 7.49 5.79 5.59 5.59
Kainga Ora 7.39 5.79 5.59 5.69
Kainga Ora - First Home Buyer Special - - - -
Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
Kiwibank 7.25 6.69 6.49 6.49
Kiwibank - Offset 7.25 - - -
Kiwibank Special 7.25 5.79 5.59 5.69
Liberty 8.59 8.69 8.79 8.94
Nelson Building Society 7.94 5.75 5.99 -
Pepper Money Advantage 10.49 - - -
Pepper Money Easy 8.69 - - -
Pepper Money Essential 8.29 - - -
SBS Bank 7.49 6.95 6.29 6.29
SBS Bank Special - 5.89 5.49 5.69
SBS Construction lending for FHB - - - -
Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
SBS FirstHome Combo 4.94 4.89 - -
SBS FirstHome Combo - - - -
SBS Unwind reverse equity ▼9.39 - - -
TSB Bank 8.19 6.49 6.39 6.39
TSB Special 7.39 5.69 5.59 5.59
Unity 7.64 5.79 5.55 -
Unity First Home Buyer special - 5.49 - -
Wairarapa Building Society 7.70 5.95 5.75 -
Westpac 7.39 6.39 6.09 6.19
Westpac Choices Everyday 7.49 - - -
Westpac Offset 7.39 - - -
Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
Westpac Special - 5.79 5.49 5.59
Median 7.49 5.79 5.69 5.69

Last updated: 18 December 2024 9:46am

About Us  |  Advertise  |  Contact Us  |  Terms & Conditions  |  Privacy Policy  |  RSS Feeds  |  Letters  |  Archive  |  Toolbox  |  Disclaimer
 
Site by Web Developer and eyelovedesign.com