tmmonline.nz  |   landlords.co.nz        About Good Returns  |  Advertise  |  Contact Us  |  Terms & Conditions  |  RSS Feeds

NZ's Financial Adviser News Centre

GR Logo
Last Article Uploaded: Saturday, December 21st, 2:19PM

Investments

rss
Latest Headlines

Borrowing question being over-simplified

Finance minister Michael Cullen explains the Government's position on debt and allegations it is borrowing to invest in the super fund.

Tuesday, June 5th 2001, 4:28PM

I want to respond next to the criticism that the government has a rising debt profile, when expressed in dollar terms, and more specifically to the suggestion that the debt and the prefunding of New Zealand Superannuation are linked, via borrowing to put money into the fund.

I have to say that a lot of that criticism is not so much a criticism of the Budget, but a criticism of the government’s long term fiscal objectives and short term fiscal intentions, masquerading as a criticism of the Budget.

 I say this with some irritation because politicians who rail against the debt track never raised this as a concern when successive Budget Policy Statements and Fiscal Strategy Reports were presented to the Finance and Expenditure Committee or to Parliament itself.

I do note, with some amusement, that the same politicians have simultaneously criticised me for spending too much and too little.

Let me put this debt business in perspective because it has become the victim of distortion through over-simplification.

The government collects revenue and incurs expenses in the course of financing its operations. Operations must meet various targets: revenue to GDP, spending to GDP and operating balance. I have always said that the operating balance must, in general, be sufficient to cover transfers into the superannuation fund. If it is not, the government must explain what it intends to do with any shortfall, and how it intends to make up for any underpayments if they occur.

In this Budget, we forecast operating surpluses of $1.4 billion in fiscal 2002, and $2.4 billion, $3.1 billion and $3.7 billion in the years after that. They are fully adequate to cover transfers into the super fund of $600 million in 2002, and $1.2 billion, $1.8 billion and $2.5 billion in the years following.

Indeed, over the four years of the forecast horizon, the forecast operating surpluses are 72 percent above the amounts needed to meet fund transfers.

Alongside its operations, the government funds its capital programme. This also needs to meet defined targets. They are gross debt to GDP, net debt to GDP and net worth targets. The debt financing will jump around. For example, refinancing hospital and housing corporation debt through central government will lower the cost of debt servicing. It will show up as an increase in Crown gross debt but not Crown net debt. Delays in (say) building new schools or prisons will show up as a fall in net debt in the current year, but this will be offset by a rise next year. Lumpy spending on re-equipping the defence forces will cause a "blip" in nominal debt when it takes place in four or five years time.

The key is to keep debt in line with declared objectives, which the Budget does.

Now I want to pose the counterfactual. What if there was some extra constraint applied to the government’s finances to say that as long as there is a superannuation fund, debt must not increase in dollar terms?

There are three scenarios.

One is that there is no fund. Under this scenario, because we are not borrowing to pay into the fund, nominal debt can increase. So if a future government borrows to restore an air strike capacity and give every school child a laptop computer, that would be fine. It would be legitimate to "borrow" to fund assets that depreciate in value but not assets that appreciate in value. That would be bizarre.

Scenario two is that it is not legitimate to increase nominal debt at all. Under this scenario we take an arbitrary moment in history – 30 June 2001 – and an arbitrary level of prices and incomes, and put a money debt straightjacket on the community for the rest of time.

As inflation continues, even at low levels, and as the economy grows, the debt to GDP ratio would gradually decline. That is a legitimate debt target to have. It is just that it is not our debt target. What Mr English seems to be saying is that we are wrong for not having a debt target that was more ambitious than even the one he had when he left office!

The argument is not about borrowing to put into the fund. It is about borrowing at all!

Scenario three is that it is not legitimate to put money into the super fund unless surpluses (and as a technicality it would require cash surpluses at that) are big enough to fund both the transfers and the full net cost of the government’s capital programme. That would be highly contractionary – requiring higher taxes or major cuts to spending programmes to boost already large surpluses.

This, though, is where the logic leads. If the opposition wants, as it says it wants, $510 million to reverse the top income tax rate, $375 million to cut company taxes, $2.4 billion to double teacher salaries, $80 million for universities, $260 million for hospitals, and on and on the wish list goes, then it must make an equivalent reduction in capital spending or else it will be "borrowing" to fund these things.

That, or it is trying to apply one set of rules for things it likes and another for things it opposes.

The Opposition may well think it has a politically populist angle, but it is showing up a hugely simplistic and dangerously distorted grasp of the fundamentals of fiscal management. It is trying to score political points, but is damaging its own credentials and credibility in the process.

Finally, I will make a few comments about the call to cut corporate taxes to 30 percent.

I won’t say a lot on this because I would like the debate on any recommendations that the Tax Review may come up with to be uncluttered. However, the clamour has been so persistent that I couldn’t claim to be responding to Budget commentary with credibility if I didn’t make some comment.

There are three responses needed.

Firstly, it is not valid to compare a 30 percent nominal company tax rate in Australia with 33 percent in New Zealand. We need to compare the burden of corporate tax in both jurisdictions. Australian corporates have other non-discretionary levies to pay, and work has not been done to explicit plus implicit taxes on both sides of the Tasman.

Secondly, it is important to identify what a lower corporate tax rate does. For New Zealand resident shareholders company tax is merely a withholding tax. They are eventually taxed at their marginal tax rate, so if a shareholder has, say, a thirty nine cent marginal tax rate the only difference between a company tax rate of 30 and 33 percent is that an extra nine rather than an extra six cents has to be paid at the end of the day.

The actual benefit of a lower company tax goes to foreign resident shareholders, for whom it is, in the main, the final tax. Leaving aside the political question of whether our fiscal priority is to give tax breaks to foreigners, the core question is whether this actually attracts any new foreign investment. Since this is a small increase in what is left over from profitable investment, is the business community really saying to me that the profit potential of investment options for foreigners here versus elsewhere is so finely balanced that this will swing deals? I doubt it, but at least we need evidence not emotion to inform that decision.

My recent experience is that after tax profits in New Zealand have been driven by factors like the level of the dollar, the weather, consumer confidence, overseas prices and the state of the world economy and a three percent tax on profits would have been swamped by these first order influences on revenues and costs.

Finally, a lower tax rate might allow higher levels of retained earnings to be reinvested. This assumes shareholders are willing to forgo dividends. Even if they are, the level of reinvestment is governed more by the prospects for future profits than by the untaxed amounts left over from past profits. In this regard, it is just as important to ensure that economic conditions, the skill system, the innovative environment and economic development initiatives create opportunities make profits. There is no benefit in even having a company tax rate of zero if there are no profits to be made.

Overall, I am happy with responses to the Budget. It presents a robust economic outlook backed by a strong fiscal position. There is some explaining to be done on some of the content, and some debate to be held on some of the options for the future. If before the Budget I had had the advantage of advice received since, I really wouldn’t have changed it. On that standard, I may not have satisfied you, but I have satisfied myself!

This is an extract of a speech made by Finance Minister Michael Cullen to the Business Herald Budget seminar.
« Fund's rules present problemsAMP & Good Returns launch superannuation website »

Special Offers

Commenting is closed

 

print

Printable version  

print

Email to a friend
News Bites
Latest Comments
  • The good guys get told off
    “I can't quite reconcile the rationale, or lack thereof, with the comments so far. Pathfinder were found to have made misleading...”
    1 day ago by John Milner
  • The good guys get told off
    “As a follow on to this conversation: I'm assuming that the Regulator will be consistent by 'naming and shaming' the other...”
    2 days ago by Pragmatic
  • The good guys get told off
    “FMA does not understand the consequences of these type of actions A number of Insurance Companies were taken to court and...”
    2 days ago by LNF
  • The good guys get told off
    “Superlife was censored for using unregistered salespeople however what is not commonly known was that the FMA were aware...”
    2 days ago by Patrickdiack
  • The good guys get told off
    “FMA executive director, Response and Enforcement, Louise Unger said:... Unger was appointed to that role in April of this...”
    3 days ago by Aggressively_passive
Subscribe Now

News and information about KiwiSaver

Previous News
Most Commented On
Mortgage Rates Table

Full Rates Table | Compare Rates

Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
AIA - Back My Build 4.94 - - -
AIA - Go Home Loans 7.49 5.79 5.49 5.59
ANZ 7.39 6.39 6.19 6.19
ANZ Blueprint to Build 7.39 - - -
ANZ Good Energy - - - 1.00
ANZ Special - 5.79 5.59 5.59
ASB Bank 7.39 5.79 5.49 5.59
ASB Better Homes Top Up - - - 1.00
Avanti Finance 7.90 - - -
Basecorp Finance 8.35 - - -
BNZ - Classic - 5.99 5.69 5.69
Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
BNZ - Mortgage One 7.54 - - -
BNZ - Rapid Repay 7.54 - - -
BNZ - Std 7.44 5.79 5.59 5.69
BNZ - TotalMoney 7.54 - - -
CFML 321 Loans ▼5.80 - - -
CFML Home Loans ▼6.25 - - -
CFML Prime Loans ▼7.85 - - -
CFML Standard Loans ▼8.80 - - -
China Construction Bank - 7.09 6.75 6.49
China Construction Bank Special - - - -
Co-operative Bank - First Home Special - 5.69 - -
Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
Co-operative Bank - Owner Occ 6.95 5.79 5.59 5.69
Co-operative Bank - Standard 6.95 6.29 6.09 6.19
Credit Union Auckland 7.70 - - -
First Credit Union Special - 5.99 5.89 -
First Credit Union Standard 7.69 6.69 6.39 -
Heartland Bank - Online 6.99 5.49 5.39 5.45
Heartland Bank - Reverse Mortgage - - - -
Heretaunga Building Society ▼8.15 ▼6.50 ▼6.30 -
ICBC 7.49 5.79 5.59 5.59
Kainga Ora 7.39 5.79 5.59 5.69
Kainga Ora - First Home Buyer Special - - - -
Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
Kiwibank 7.25 6.69 6.49 6.49
Kiwibank - Offset 7.25 - - -
Kiwibank Special 7.25 5.79 5.59 5.69
Liberty 8.59 8.69 8.79 8.94
Nelson Building Society 7.94 5.75 5.99 -
Pepper Money Advantage 10.49 - - -
Pepper Money Easy 8.69 - - -
Pepper Money Essential 8.29 - - -
SBS Bank 7.49 6.95 6.29 6.29
SBS Bank Special - 5.89 5.49 5.69
SBS Construction lending for FHB - - - -
Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
SBS FirstHome Combo 4.94 4.89 - -
SBS FirstHome Combo - - - -
SBS Unwind reverse equity ▼9.39 - - -
TSB Bank 8.19 6.49 6.39 6.39
TSB Special 7.39 5.69 5.59 5.59
Unity 7.64 5.79 5.55 -
Unity First Home Buyer special - 5.49 - -
Wairarapa Building Society 7.70 5.95 5.75 -
Westpac 7.39 6.39 6.09 6.19
Westpac Choices Everyday 7.49 - - -
Westpac Offset 7.39 - - -
Lender Flt 1yr 2yr 3yr
Westpac Special - 5.79 5.49 5.59
Median 7.49 5.79 5.69 5.69

Last updated: 18 December 2024 9:46am

About Us  |  Advertise  |  Contact Us  |  Terms & Conditions  |  Privacy Policy  |  RSS Feeds  |  Letters  |  Archive  |  Toolbox  |  Disclaimer
 
Site by Web Developer and eyelovedesign.com